Showing posts with label The Redistribution Recession. Show all posts
Showing posts with label The Redistribution Recession. Show all posts

Saturday, January 16, 2021

The Fallacy of the Heap Returns

The (il)logic of Obamaeconomics has returned:

  • Each $100 of weekly unemployment bonus has hardly any negative effect (some might say "no statistically significant effect") on employment or GDP.
  • Food stamp benefits have hardly any negative effect on employment or GDP.
  • Rental assistance has hardly any negative effect on employment or GDP.
  • Obamacare subsidies have hardly any negative effect on employment or GDP.
  • Minimum wage increases have hardly any negative effect on employment or GDP.
  • A new negative income tax has hardly any negative effect on employment or GDP.
My writings rarely express disagreement with any of the bullets by themselves.  For the sake of argument, I am not disputing them here.

Where I disagree is the assertion that the combination of all of the bullets, which is Biden's pandemic relief proposal, would have hardly any negative effect on employment or GDP.  We could talk about the convexity of deadweight costs, and the fact that the new redistribution goes on top of a lot of redistribution in the baseline, but this point was well known even among the noneconomist ancients.  It is the fallacy of the heap.

Every Econ 101 teacher has to confront this fallacy.  Invariably every class has a student pushing back on the law of demand, "Raise the price of a car by a penny and that will not stop anyone from purchasing the car."  Teacher has to say, OK let the seller of the car raise the price $10,000, just one penny at a time.  Each penny increase has no effect on sales ... therefore $10K has no effect on sales.

Economists  beware of vague predicates!  Biden's smorgasbord of redistribution will noticeably reduce employment and GDP.

Wednesday, February 28, 2018

Honey, Who Shrank the Economic Pie?

Copyright, TheHill.com

Last week the White House released the latest Economic Report of the President that, following both statute and tradition, begins with a short letter to Congress from President Trump, followed by the detailed annual report of his Council of Economic Advisers.

The period from 2010 should have had relatively rapid growth as the economy recovered from the 2008-09 recession, but it did not. Both the president's letter and the CEA annual report blame the slow growth on federal policy failures during the previous administration.

A lot of research backs up their claim and suggests that higher growth rates are forthcoming if only some of those failures are reversed and not too many new ones are created.

First is the high statutory corporate tax rate that had prevailed for decades prior to 2017 (yes, the "effective rate" was not as high, but a low effective rate is just a symptom of some of the growth-retarding effects of corporate-income taxation.)

The Obama administration agreed that America would benefit if the federal statutory rate were reduced, saying that a reduction would be "as close to a free lunch as tax reformers will ever get."
But they were not enough interested in corporate tax reform to reach a deal with Congress, so the long-overdue rate cut has President Trump's signature on it and is expect to add to economic growth over the next several years.

Second was the so-called federal "stimulus" law of 2009 that was supposed to jumpstart the recovery. But, unlike the stimulus laws in some other countries, such as the United Kingdom, our stimulus did not expand the economic pie by enhancing incentives.

Instead, our stimulus was a redistribution exercise that eroded incentives to work and earn income by expanding food stamps, mortgage subsidies, health insurance assistance and unemployment assistance primarily for people who were unemployed or otherwise had low incomes (the end of the Bush administration did some of this too). The result was less work and less national income for as long as the stimulus lasted.

Third, very soon after the stimulus expired, a new permanent redistribution began to take effect in the form of the Affordable Care Act (ACA). Indeed, the health-insurance assistance provisions of the ACA were presaged in the 2009 stimulus.

As its authors attempt to target assistance to people who they thought needed it most, the ACA unleashes a host of unintended consequences that shrink the economic pie in the process of redistributing it.

Businesses are encouraged to forgo hiring in order to keep their employment below 50 full-time equivalents and to cut workers' hours in order to keep the workweek less than 30 hours. Productive and knowledgeable employees are encouraged to retire early in order to be eligible for taxpayer-funded assistance.

The ACA is also remarkably uneven in its treatment of different sectors, regions and workplace circumstances. Another result is therefore a misallocation of resources away from the most penalized activities to the most favored ones, thereby depressing productivity; i.e., the amount of value that workers create in the marketplace.

Most businesses and households did not react to these incentives because other considerations were dominant, but it only takes a small percent of them who do to make a noticeable dent in the growth rate. If and when the federal government can repeal the ACA or relax its growth-retarding provisions, that will add to the growth rate.

Fourth, other regulations came into effect during the Obama years. Perhaps the leading instance is the 2010 Dodd-Frank financial regulation law. The law is so remarkably complicated that research on its effects will be ongoing for years, and massive complexity is hardly the leading ingredient for economic growth.

But it is likely that new financial regulations have reduced the willingness of banks to lend to small and medium-sized businesses, which further restrains economic activity.

The national economic pie has been smaller due to Obama-era policies, leaving opportunities for subsequent federal policies to enhance economic performance.

Casey Mulligan is a professor of economics at the University of Chicago. His recent research has focused on non-pecuniary incentives to save and work and how the economy affects policy. His two recent books are, "The Redistribution Recession: How Labor Market Distortions Contracted the Economy," and "Side Effects: The Economic Consequences of the Health Reform."

Saturday, April 1, 2017

Machine proves Paul Krugman wrong about the recession

Click for short video

Click for short video


For more on the two "sides" to this argument, see

See more examples of economics questions answered by machine.

Tuesday, January 24, 2017

Who wrote this?

"High social transfers not tied to work incentives emerged as the most likely explanation for the low participation rate. The phase-in of ... minimum wage ... may have also helped to drive down participation rates."


But the Brookings Institution, which refused to consider nationwide explanations like mine, wrote this!

about Puerto Rico (see p. 29)!

Friday, July 22, 2016

Saturday, December 12, 2015

Timothy Jost poses an economics question

In reading the [CBO's analysis of ACA marginal tax rates and the labor market], questions that occurred to me, admittedly a non-economist, included why there is no accounting for the increased employment of health care workers which surely must accompany the coverage expansions?

The answer is:
  • when we redistribute income for the purposes of paying for some people's health care, that likely creates additional jobs in the process of supplying health care to the ACA beneficiaries.
  • But we cannot forget about the other end of the redistribution. Somebody is paying for this, either by paying taxes or loaning money to the government, and that's funds that the payers cannot spend on other things. So there's a reduction in the employment of people who would be supplying the payers (whatever it was that they would have spent money on: anything from food to forming new businesses).
  • The bottom line for labor demand hinges on a comparison of the labor-intensity of healthcare supply and the intensity of supplying those other things.

In effect, CBO and many others assume that they are equally labor intensive, so that there is no net aggregate-labor-demand effect. Only the composition of labor demand is changed.  (If I had to say how the "true" comparison works, I would say that just about anything for low-income people is less labor-intensive than the things bought by high-income people, but this gap is small in comparison to the marginal tax rate effects).


I also addressed a similar question in my earlier Redistribution Recession.

Mr. Jost has been so busy digesting and summarizing ACA regulations (that you for that, sir!) that he probably hasn't had time to look at my books on the economics of Obama-era social programs.

Monday, February 23, 2015

Opeds about Redistribution and Obamacare

I published three opeds in the Wall Street Journal, but do not reproduce them here in real time to be consistent with WSJ's copyright. Here are some shortcuts to ungated versions:


Tuesday, March 4, 2014

Sell your copy of the Redistribution Recession!

sell your hard copy of the Redistribution Recession! There is a severe shortage and as far as I can tell used copies are going for $100.


When the publisher starts shipping again next month (they promised me that they will never charge more than $40), I recommend buying multiple copies so that you get more revenue during the next shortage.

If you don't already have a copy: what were you thinking?!

Thursday, December 12, 2013

JEL Review of The Redistribution Recession

“Somewhere, Milton Friedman is smiling.
Casey Mulligan ... has provided an unalloyed Chicago-style explanation for the U.S. economy’s poor performance during and immediately after the Great Recession.”

-Read the rest of Christopher L. Foote's review (jump to p. 1194).

Links to other reviews of the book.

Tuesday, September 17, 2013

Comprehensive book review by Richard V. Burkhauser

Professor Richard V. Burkhauser has written a comprehensive review of The Redistribution Recession.  I should be reading his books rather than the other way around, but nonetheless he read it from cover to cover and has summaries and evaluations of every single chapter.

Saturday, June 8, 2013

Subsidizing Layoffs

I noticed this in an Urban Institute report:

Some large‐firm interviewees reported that before ARRA they provided some amount of free or reduced cost COBRA coverage for laid‐off workers, based upon the prior duration of employment. ...Several of these companies reported that they reduced or dropped this prior benefit in reaction to ARRA.

In other words, these employers normally were paying for health insurance for workers they laid off, but for a while (from April 2009 to May 2010) the ARRA picked up the tab. This is yet another reason why laying people off during the recession was cheaper than layoffs normally are.

Friday, February 15, 2013

Testimony on Work Incentives, the Recovery Act, and the Economy

Overview (about 5.5 minutes)
Do Transfers Stimulate the Economy? (about 2.5 minutes) Politically Incorrect (about 3 minutes) Will the ACA affect employment? (about 2 minutes) Unemployment isn't fun (about 1 minute) What are the effects of payroll subsidies? (less than one minute) Written testimony here.

Tuesday, January 22, 2013

Welfare Arithmetic Event Tomorrow




EVENT TOMORROW: American Action Forum Event Will Examine Stimulus Spending Effects on Welfare Efficacy




 

High Res Forum Logo





***EVENT TOMORROW***

 

American Action Forum Event Will Examine Stimulus Spending Effects on Welfare Efficacy

 

Speakers Include Jared Bernstein, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities; Casey Mulligan, University of Chicago; Shannon Mok, Congressional Budget Office
 

WASHINGTON - The American Action Forum (@AAF) will host an event tomorrow, Wednesday, January 23 examining the link between stimulus spending and welfare efficacy. University of Chicago Professor Casey Mulligan will first present findings from his recent paper, “The ARRA: Some Unpleasant Welfare Arithmetic.”  Following the presentation, AAF’s Director of Fiscal Policy, Gordon Gray, will moderate a discussion on the paper’s implications between Jared Bernstein of the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities and key contributor to the design of The ARRA and Shannon Mok of the Congressional Budget Office and lead author of a recent CBO report on effective marginal tax rates on low and middle income workers. RSVP here. Watch live online here.

 

WHEN: Wednesday, January 23th from 9:00AM – 10:30AM

 

WHAT: Getting Employment Incentives Right: ARRA and Marginal Effective Tax Rates

 

WHERE:

 

National Press Club, Holeman Lounge

529 14th Street Northwest

Washington, DC 20045



RSVP: http://arra.eventbrite.com/#



LIVE STREAM: http://www.visualwebcaster.com/event.asp?id=91799

 

AGENDA

 

8:30 AM: Doors open, breakfast will be served

 

9:00 AM Presentation: “The ARRA: Some Unpleasant Welfare Arithmetic”

 

Casey Mulligan, University of Chicago

 

Discussants:

 

Jared Bernstein, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities

Shannon Mok, Congressional Budget Office

 

Panel discussion will include time for audience questions.

 

Moderator:

 

Gordon Gray, American Action Forum

 

10:30 AM Conclusion



For press inquiries, contact Noelle Clemente at nclemete@americanactionforum.org or 240-888-7310.

 


 

 


 


















Try Email Marketing with VerticalResponse!





Saturday, January 19, 2013

The Redistribution Recession in Video Format

Watch the 28 minute video offering an overview of the main arguments and results from The Redistribution Recession.


hosted by youtube

(NOTE: Setting quality to 720 HD gives the best resolution)

Sunday, January 13, 2013

Washington DC area Events coming up

DC-area events related to The Redistribution Recession:

Sunday, December 2, 2012

Redistribution Recession Episode of the Robert Wenzel Show



I jump the video ahead to the 8:38 mark because it consists of a full 8 minutes digression on the month-to-month time path of the money supply during 2008.  Rewind if you want to hear that part.

Saturday, December 1, 2012

Why Doesn't UI Stimulate? 7 Min Podcast

WLS AM Don Wade and Roma 7 min podcast

Highlights
  • Law of Unintended Consequences
  • 99 weeks of UI is only one of many program expansions
  • The labor market is not a zero sum game

Sunday, November 25, 2012

Recession by Redistribution


Doubt of the benefit
Why increasing unemployment aid is prolonging the recession

By CASEY B. MULLIGAN

More families used food stamps this past Thanksgiving than ever in history, while Congress is pushing to extend benefits — again — for the longterm unemployed.

But what if such aid isn’t helping us weather the recession, but instead prolonging it?

The White House, and other believers in Keynesian policy refer to subsidies to the unemployed, poor and financially distressed as “automatic stabilizers” and insist that subsidies have a large positive effect on national income.

Yet when the subsidy spigots were opened wide in 2008 and 2009, labor market activity contracted sharply, and stubbornly refuses to rebound.

Getty Images
It is time to reconsider the old-school economic idea that paying people to be unemployed reduces employment. The more we pay poor people, the more poor people we will have. The more we help people and institutions in financial distress, the more financial distress there will be.

It is easy to look at a particular instance of redistribution — say, unemployment benefits — and conclude that its aggregate effects are minimal, or approximately zero. But policymakers did not expand just one provision of one program.

Food-stamp recipients were given a big raise in October 2008, and then another raise six months later. Thanks to the elimination of asset-testing by the majority of states, just about anyone who is the sole earner in their household now find themselves eligible for food stamps during periods of unemployment.

The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act, popularly known as the stimulus, gave unemployment insurance recipients a weekly bonus, and offered to pay for the majority of their health insurance expenses. FDIC and Treasury reduced some “unaffordable” mortgage payments, which means that successful people need not apply. The list goes on and on.

The essential consequence for all of these is the same: a reduction in the reward to activities and efforts that raise incomes.

I’ve studied how redistribution affects the “reward” for working.

We start with a monthly index of government benefits. Before the recession began, an unemployed person typically received about $10,000 a year in government benefits. By the end of 2009, program rule changes alone had increased the typical benefit to almost $16,000.



Plot that against the hours an average American adult spends away from work in a year (the difference between total hours in a year and hours at work). Largely because of the increase in the number of people without jobs, the average work hours were about 120 fewer at the end of 2009 than they were at the end of 2007 — a 10% decline.

But things start to change at the beginning of 2010. Slowly, the number of hours of work by the average American begins to climb. Not coincidentally, the average annual government benefit for the unemployed dropped to $14,000.

The increase in benefits provides a disincentive to work. From 2007 until 2009, I found a startling 13% decline in the “reward” for working — that is, how much better the average job would be over collecting benefits.

Considering that, why is the labor market still so far from a full recovery? Because government benefits are still far from returning to pre-recession levels.

But wait, a Keynesian would say. Unemployment benefits are good for the economy overall, since it is money spent and not saved.

It’s true that the poor and unemployed tend to quickly spend what they have on basic needs. Yet Keynesians have gone further to claim that spending patterns of the poor are why redistribution raises total spending and thereby employment. Redistribution changes the composition of spending and employment in the direction of industries like discount groceries and low-cost retail that disproportionately serve poor customers and away from industries like, say, airlines. The stimulating effects of benefit spending for the overall economy is limited.

Redistribution is not free. Redistribution depresses employment, aggregate spending and GDP, by implicitly punishing the successful and implicitly rewarding the unsuccessful.

We don’t like to see people suffer, and it’s a natural instinct to want to increase redistribution in a time of recession. But the better economic solution reduces the implicit penalties of government aid, and gets more people working, so they don’t need the help.

Casey B. Mulligan is a professor of economics at the University of Chicago and author of the new book “The Redistribution Recession” (Oxford University Press); redistributionrecession.com

Friday, November 9, 2012

Blind Squirrel Finds No Food

It's a good sign that there are critics of The Redistribution Recession, and that so far every one of them admits that he hasn't read any of it. I'm trying to think about how I could encourage such behavior, because any citation is a good citation.

With enough attempted criticisms and a little luck, the law of large numbers predicts that non-reading critics will eventually put forward something that might be valid. That's what's impressive about this admitted non-reader's piece: it makes quite a few claims about the book and every single one of them is false! I'm sure because I HAVE read the book ... many times.

(please click through to take a look: it has a nice picture and page views are the reward I mentioned above)

Example: The book allegedly does not address specific criticisms (without reading a book, how do you know what's missing from it?), when in fact I anticipated these criticisms years ago and devote entire chapters of the book to them.  (Oxford owns the copyright, and I will not steal from them in order to further help non-readers by reprinting or paraphrasing those chapters here or elsewhere on the internet.)

I understand that reading takes time, so in order to help the blind squirrels find an acorn every once in a while, I have prepared a www page (with Oxford's permission) with a brief summary of the book, a brief Q & A about the book, and a short video presentation.


Another alternative, or prelude, to reading: take a look at the opinions of some people who have read the book, or are currently reading it:

"Rethinking one's views" is even more costly than regular reading, which is one more reason to talk, blog, or curse about the book without actually reading any of it.  Even opening to page one could prove to be expensive. 


Tuesday, November 6, 2012

Professor Quiggin Could Learn a Lot from My Book

I recently criticized Paul Krugman's recent book for ignoring marginal tax rates, which were hiked by the stimulus law and would be further hiked by the bigger stimulus that he proposes in his book. Moreover, I asserted that high marginal tax rates are responsible for a lot of the U.S. labor market's recent depression, and that Krugman's plan would have depressed it further.

Although not the author I was criticizing, Professor Quiggin recently wrote that


  1. I was obviously wrong because of what happened in other countries,
  2. The very recent (last 6 months or so), withdraw of some of the 99 weeks of UI benefits proves that marginal tax rates don't matter, and
  3. "As for food stamps, the expansion in the number of recipients is not due to changes in policy."


All of these points are addressed  in my book, before Professor Quiggin even wrote them.  Even if he had not read my book, a little investigation would have quickly shown him that his claims are incorrect. I take the points in reverse order.

3.  SNAP (aka, food stamps). Professor Quiggin has been repeatedly refuted by the US Department of Agriculture (it administers SNAP), most recently in its Sept 2011 report where it says "The continued growth in SNAP participation from 2009 to 2010 is likely attributable to the slow recovery from the recent economic recession, expansions in SNAP eligibility, and continued outreach efforts."  [emphasis added]  My book agrees that all three were a factor, provides estimates of their separate quantitative importance (Table 3.4), and discusses the academic literature on the subject.

One way to quickly see how Professor Quiggin is wrong about food stamps is to look at SNAP participation as a ratio to either (a) persons in poverty, (b) persons on Medicaid, (c) persons on SSI, or (d) persons on SSDI.  Of course a "bad economy" expands participation all of these things, but why would SNAP grow so much more than the others?  The answer is simple: SNAP policy changed, while the definition of poverty was constant and the policy rules for Medicaid, SSI, and SSDI were relatively constant.

2.  99 weeks no more.  As of October 2012, unemployed people could not collect 99 weeks UI, thanks to UI rule changes going into effect this spring.  But they still could collect 60+ weeks, not to mention remain on Medicaid, SNAP, and other programs indefinitely.  My book quantifies all of these factors, and finds that the difference between 60+ weeks and 99 weeks (actually, 96 weeks was the national average) is real but fairly small (extending UI from 26 to 52 weeks is a big deal).  So my model predicts that, adjusted for age and other factors, the labor market would rebound slightly during 2012, which is exactly what happened.  (There are also issues of timing here, which are discussed in my book).

3.  Austerity depresses the economy.  I agree (see also here) that European governments have typically failed to revive their economies, and probably further depressed them.  But austerity is not opposite of redistribution (ie, hiking marginal tax rates).  Think of how austerity might be implemented in the U.S.: we might cut Medicare and Social Security, but only for the more successful beneficiaries.  Regardless of whether redistribution is achieved by withholding benefits from families with high incomes, providing more subsidies to families with low incomes, or both, an essential consequence is the same: a reduction in the reward to activities and efforts that raise incomes.  Many kinds of austerity enhance redistribution, and that’s an important reason why austerity depresses the labor market.

With that said, I am very much in favor of cross-country comparisons.  I would love it if Professor Quiggin or anyone else measured marginal tax rate time series for any country that we could compare to my series for the U.S.  But Professor Quiggin has failed to do that, and instead  claims without evidence that marginal tax rates were constant (or falling) everywhere outside the U.S.

Finally, if marginal tax rates were found to be constant in Estonia (the only specific country that Professor Quiggin points to), does that mean that marginal tax rates do not matter in the U.S.?  Please let me know so I can notify American economists that Estonia is our ideal laboratory, and notify policymakers that they can safety hike marginal tax rates to 100 percent without noticeable consequences.

Added: I have heard the claim that the ratio of SNAP to Medicaid increased so sharply because Medicaid was cut sharply, rather that SNAP changing its rules.  The claim ignores the help that Medicaid got from ARRA and, more important, that Medicaid spending and participation per person in poverty was pretty flat.  Why don't the allegedly sharp Medicaid cuts result in sharply less Medicaid per person in poverty?  The answer is simple: Medicaid cuts, if any, where nowhere near the magnitude of SNAP expansions.  For more on SNAP expansions, see The Redistribution Recession.