Wednesday, December 27, 2017
Some Immediate Benefits of the Corporate Tax Cut
Monday, December 18, 2017
At 21% or 20%, new corporate tax rate will boost US economy
Monday, November 20, 2017
The ACA's Employer Penalty is Distorting Business
Monday, November 13, 2017
Low effective rate not an argument against corporate tax cut
Sunday, November 5, 2017
Does Communism have a universal constant? From the October Revolution to Bernie Sanders
[Communists] openly declare that their ends can be attained only by the forcible overthrow of all existing social conditions. Let the ruling classes tremble at a Communistic revolution. The proletarians have nothing to lose but their chains. They have a world to win. Working men of all countries, unite!
It is not so easy to have a government that tightly controls economic resources, but is unable and unwilling to exercise control over ideas.
Friday, November 3, 2017
Stanford University findings on the ACA and the labor market
"While the Affordable Care Act had a significant effect on health insurance coverage, it did not have a substantial effect on the U.S. labor market as many had expected" and
"the Affordable Care Act has not had the negative effect on jobs the law’s critics claimed it would."
He was referring to a working paper distributed by the National Bureau Economic of Research, which states that
“labor market outcomes in the aggregate were not significantly affected.”
- Table 4 (the paper's first table on labor market outcomes) shows that the ACA reduced nationwide labor force participation by 349,190 in 2016, plus however much the ACA reduced labor force participation in a geographic area that was fully insured before the ACA, which I call the HFIA (Hypothetically Fully Insured Area). This effect is economically significant and, when combined with items (2) and (3) below, is easily in line with "the negative effect on jobs that the law's critics claimed it would be."
[Admittedly, the 349,190 is probably not statistically significant by the usual criteria, but the quotes above are not claiming that either side could be correct. Rather they claim to decisively reject "critics" who made claims right in line with the Duggan-Goda-Jackson point estimate. See below for the derivation of the 349,190]
- The paper assumes, without much explanation, that the HFIA part of the ACA's impact is zero. But other work has shown that near-elderly insured people were given a tremendous incentive to retire early. In other words, basic economics tells us that the HFIA part is likely positive (i.e., in the same direction as the 349,190) and we should not assume it to be close to zero until we have further measurement.
- The empirical methods in the paper, which emphasize differences among geographic areas such as Medicaid expansion states versus other states, are not designed to detect effects of the employer penalty. The employer penalty is the same amount throughout the nation. The penalty creates large labor-market distortions; those distortions that have been measured in other studies have proven to be similar across geographic areas. Moreover, the employer penalty did not apply until the 2016 coverage year, whereas 8/9 of the working paper's data is before that date. This is an especially serious problem for the low-income population, where the employer penalty in effect has them working 50-60 days per year for the government, on top of the implicit and explicit employment/income taxes they would pay even without the ACA (this fact is nowhere mentioned in the paper). For this reason, the authors' claim than that "lower income individuals were actually incentivized to work more" is especially incredible.
Tuesday, October 24, 2017
Delong and Krugman make "math error", while falsely accusing Greg Mankiw of making math error!
[Unlike DeLong, Krugman does not actually use the word "static." He says "direct" -- it is possible that he understands Furman's static and Krugman's direct to be different, and just failed to indicate the distinction to his readers.
It's fine if he prefers his blue rectangle to Furman's "static" revenue loss, but remember that by all accounts the blue rectangle is about $400b/year -- close to CEA's estimate of the wage gain.
In other words, when you change to the blue-rectangle definition of "static" you not only reduce the theoretical Furman ratio by a factor of (1-t), you also increase the static revenue number by the same factor. The CEA's $4k per family is fixed.
This is like measuring things in yards or meters or fathoms -- the standard you choose does not change the answer, as long as you are consistent about the standard ... let's watch to see if they are.]
Later Krugman talks about yet another concept of revenue loss, namely the actual (a.k.a., dynamic) loss. Mankiw had already explained the static-dynamic distinction to his readers. This morning I tried to help Mr. Krugman with this by posting on his twitter:
What @delong is seeing is that "static" revenue loss is arbitrary:
the static revenue loss from a per-unit tax cut [what Krugman shows with his blue rectangle and calls "direct"]
is different from [Furman's] static loss from an ad valorem tax cut [what a corporate-income tax cut would be],
even when those cuts are scaled so that both have the same effects on revenue and the surplus of all parties.
That is why I use actual revenue loss.
You may also be interested in a previous instance when, with important public-policy issues at stake, Krugman failed to appreciate what supply and demand really says and neglected to admit his error.
Sunday, October 22, 2017
What does Summers 1981 say about the long-run incidence of the corporate-income tax?
Contrary to Summer's claim, this result is not "unprecedented in analyses of tax incidence" rather it is one of the most ubiquitous results in analyses of tax incidence.
Notice that Summers' response this morning fails to claim that I am wrong about the LONG-RUN incidence in HIS MODEL (It should already be obvious that I am not wrong -- my early post already provided the algebraic analysis of, and precise citation to, the relevant equation from his paper).
- He claims that "Mulligan also fails to recognize that a corporate rate cut benefits capital and hurts labor outside the corporate sector because it draws capital out of the noncorporate sector, raising its marginal productivity and reducing that of labor." [emphasis added] But of course I did -- it is my item (C) -- and pointed readers to one of Summers supply-side-economics papers on that very subject.
- He claims that Greg and I overestimate the effect of Trump's plan on the incentive to invest (see his "a cut in the corporate tax rate from 35 to 20 percent in the presence of expensing of substantial or total investment has very little impact on the incentive to invest"). But Greg and I are looking at INFINITESIMAL changes -- it doesn't get any smaller than that!
Regarding Summers other points this morning, not specific to Summers 1981, I had already anticipated them.
Public Policy Suffers when Price Theory is Ignored
- can give quantitative answers. Greg Mankiw writes "I must confess that I am amazed at how simply this [quantitative formula] turns out. In particular, I do not have much intuition for why, for example, the answer does not depend on the production function." Supply and demand can answer his question, without any algebra.
- can deal with complexities, such as "imperfect competition." The simple supply and demand model assumes perfect competition, but that assumption can be and has been modified. Guess what?! Making that modification shows that even the simply supply and demand model, let alone the proclamations of Furman-Summers-Krugman, understates the wage impact of capital-income taxation.
[Hints: what new rectangles appear when the factor-renter is selling his product for more than marginal cost? What determines the equilibrium size of those rectangles? Why should we use the corporate tax to rather than the DOJ to fight monopoly?] - can deal with complexities, such as debt finance. Having uneven taxation of different types of capital tends to reduce the denominator of the Furman ratio more than it reduces the numerator. i.e., Furman still has it even more backwards than I thought (update: Summers too).
- explains why horizontal capital supply is not an "extreme" case. Gary Becker and I explained why capital supply probably slopes down somewhat in the long run (thanks Kevin M. Murphy for reminding me about this -- not to mention for teaching so many of us about price theory!)
- shows you how to process the economic data. Furman and Krugman make evidence-free proclamations about the elasticity of capital supply. Supply and demand shows what economic data is needed to measure that elasticity (spoiler: it's not complicated, and shows a very high elasticity).
Update: 2 hours later Summers posted a reply that reiterates the "it's complicated," "monopoly profits," and "debt finance" excuses for ignoring what the simple model says. See my points 2 and 3 above.
He also hopes that you forget that he referred to CEA's result -- which is generally in agreement with the simple supply and demand model -- as "unprecedented in analyses of tax incidence."
Regarding Summers' other replies, see here.
Wednesday, October 18, 2017
Furman and Summers revoke Summers' academic work on investment
Furman and Summers have it backwards. They don't seem to understand that the wage gains from a cut come not only from the Treasury but also the economic waste created by the corporate tax.
Note that Summers now calls the 250% "unprecedented in analyses of tax incidence," yet I am getting it from his own paper about how the corporate-income tax works (see esp. p. 95)!
Update on (C): Greg Mankiw points out still more labor benefits not shown in the picture. His source -- you guessed it! -- Larry Summers.
(update: Summers' reply now revokes academic work more generally. He also wants you to forget that he said CEA's Furman-ratio result to be "unprecedented in analyses of tax incidence."
Moreover, he digs his hole deeper with his critiques of the simple model. I.e., President Trump should be thanking Summers for unwittingly strengthening the case for corporate tax reform.
See my comments on Summers 1981 here.)