The elasticity of housing supply is the effect on the flow of home building (measured as a log change -- think of it as a percentage change) of the inflation-adjusted purchase price of housing (also measured as a log change).
The elasticity has long been studied in economics; one of the seminal studies was published by Professors Topel and Rosen in 1988.
The most recent (2000-2005) housing boom was a boom in both housing prices and construction -- was it a movement (albeit, further) along the same sort of supply curve as in previous housing cycles?
Unfortunately, I have noted before that various housing price indices disagree widely about the magnitude of the housing price boom. The Case-Shiller index (adjusted for general inflation as measured by the PCE deflator), says that housing prices were 0.56 log points (about 75%) .17higher in 2005 than they were in 2000. The OFHEO index says 0.27 log points. The Census Bureau quality-adjusted index of the selling prices of new homes (the index used in the Topel-Rosen study) says 0.17 log points. The BEA price index for new residential structures says 0.15 log points.
Because the indices give such different estimates of housing price changes, they would give equally different estimates of the supply elasticity. So, in order to answer the question, it is crucial that I stick with the index used by Topel and Rosen.
Real residential investment per capita increased 0.24 log points. So that implies a supply elasticity of 1.4 for the period 2000-2005.
Topel and Rosen found significant lags in the response of investment to housing prices, whereas the boom and bust since 2000 interestingly show housing construction and housing prices to change direction in essentially the same month.
Putting that aside, Topel and Rosen find a 1.0 supply elasticity with respect to a housing price elevation that lasts one year, a 1.6 elasticity for a 4-year elevation, and a 1.7 elasticity for a 8-year elevation. So that looks pretty close to what happened in the recent boom, occurring after Topel and Rosen wrote.
[Technical note: to adjust for trends, Topel and Rosen put a linear (NOT exponential) trend in a level-of-investment regression. That is not appropriate here -- would be very sensitive to which years were included -- so I normalized investment by population]
The elasticity has long been studied in economics; one of the seminal studies was published by Professors Topel and Rosen in 1988.
The most recent (2000-2005) housing boom was a boom in both housing prices and construction -- was it a movement (albeit, further) along the same sort of supply curve as in previous housing cycles?
Unfortunately, I have noted before that various housing price indices disagree widely about the magnitude of the housing price boom. The Case-Shiller index (adjusted for general inflation as measured by the PCE deflator), says that housing prices were 0.56 log points (about 75%) .17higher in 2005 than they were in 2000. The OFHEO index says 0.27 log points. The Census Bureau quality-adjusted index of the selling prices of new homes (the index used in the Topel-Rosen study) says 0.17 log points. The BEA price index for new residential structures says 0.15 log points.
Because the indices give such different estimates of housing price changes, they would give equally different estimates of the supply elasticity. So, in order to answer the question, it is crucial that I stick with the index used by Topel and Rosen.
Real residential investment per capita increased 0.24 log points. So that implies a supply elasticity of 1.4 for the period 2000-2005.
Topel and Rosen found significant lags in the response of investment to housing prices, whereas the boom and bust since 2000 interestingly show housing construction and housing prices to change direction in essentially the same month.
Putting that aside, Topel and Rosen find a 1.0 supply elasticity with respect to a housing price elevation that lasts one year, a 1.6 elasticity for a 4-year elevation, and a 1.7 elasticity for a 8-year elevation. So that looks pretty close to what happened in the recent boom, occurring after Topel and Rosen wrote.
[Technical note: to adjust for trends, Topel and Rosen put a linear (NOT exponential) trend in a level-of-investment regression. That is not appropriate here -- would be very sensitive to which years were included -- so I normalized investment by population]
Don't you think this sort of analysis of price change and elasticity only makes sense with data from a single location? I mean, averaging the data for the boom in Florida and in Detroit will not help come up with a significant conclusion. Analyzing data from Detroit and Florida and New York and Los Angeles and Houston... would not only give you a more significant (statistically) result because of lower variation and better correlation, but would also give you some guide for how elasticity varies with the magnitude of the boom. Texas = relatively small boom vs Miami.
ReplyDeleteYou could even consider cities in other countries that had a housing boom at more or less the same time.
My JME paper on the price of land with Jonathan Heathcote (Minneapolis Fed) reconcile these data.
ReplyDeleteBest,
Morris A. Davis
University of Wisconsin
My brother Attends exams at University of Florida he will write facts about this article as he Depends on it for good marks
ReplyDeleteThus, an predicted 40 % improve in actual estate support expenditure could increase property costs by more than 40 % in the short run. bubblegum casting
ReplyDeleteThank you publishing comparative information and its now becoming simpler to finish this task. Chris Rene is presented in Songs Choice's "Primed" sequence bubblegum casting
ReplyDelete